Foreign Direct Investment and hot labour markets: Raising the bar

Foreign Direct Investment and hot labour markets: Raising the bar. In the Big Tech era, knowledge-intensive companies are attracting strong inflows of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). Their rapid development is combined with the search for the best talent in order to maintain leadership.  Professor Nigel Driffield, Warwick Business School, explores the implications of this phenomenon in terms of impact on domestic employment and skilled labour earnings.

In the Big Tech era, knowledge-intensive companies are attracting strong inflows of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). Their rapid development is combined with the search for the best talent in order to maintain leadership. Nigel Driffield, Professor of International Business at Warwick Business School, explores the implications of this phenomenon in terms of impact on domestic employment and skilled labour earnings.

Foreign Direct Investment and hot labour markets: Raising the bar by CoBS Editor Pavan Jambai. Related research: FDI in hot labour markets: The implications of the war for talent, Bettina Becker , Nigel Driffield , Sandra Lancheros, James H. Love ; Journal of International Business Policy (2020) 3, 107–133.

Clues to business triumph

Every business strives for success. In the face of intense competition, firms are constantly seeking to gain competitive advantage in the global market. And in order to achieve this, they need high performers: managers with advanced skills in decision-making and strategic planning. However, obtaining that advantage appears to be a stumbling block on the way to market success. Even leading firms report significant skills shortages in key areas – advanced manufacturing, R&D, finance, supply change and many others.

Since the 1990s firms have been increasingly engaged in a global ‘war for talent’, especially in sectors related to science, technology and innovation, with technology firms seeing the highest value added per head and the highest levels of wage growth from the early 2000s on. These firms in particular hunt for the best graduates from top universities. And when competition is based on innovation rather than price, skilled labour is a crucial element of market success.

Interestingly, technology firms are becoming more concentrated in their geographies. Multinational firms, as well as new startups, are now chasing the same research centers, often attempting to build on existing agglomerations such as Silicon Valley in San Francisco, Medicon Valley in Denmark, or the ‘Golden triangle’ in the UK. Moreover, innovative industries are concentrated in a limited number of locations. For the regions concerned, this results in a higher competition for labour and, consequently, higher wages.

These days, technological clusters are developing at a fast pace. As such, high-tech firms attract large amounts of FDI – one of the factors that boosts their development. Investors purchase local companies directly or locate business activities abroad through subsidiaries. In developed countries during the1991-2012 period, foreign investment stock in high-tech industries grew 12% faster than the market average and 81% faster than FDI in manufacturing sectors. This continuous expansion subsequently requires more workforce, and it seems that an increasing number of firms are becoming involved in a global ‘war for talent’.

Hidden pitfalls

Hidden pitfals! Foreign Direct Investment and hot labour markets: Raising the bar. In the Big Tech era, knowledge-intensive companies are attracting strong inflows of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). Their rapid development is combined with the search for the best talent in order to maintain leadership.  Professor Nigel Driffield, Warwick Business School, explores the implications of this phenomenon in terms of impact on domestic employment and skilled labour earnings.

But what makes Tech so special? For, one, labour market conditions are specific in technology- and research-intensive industries. Already scarce, skilled labour is therefore better paid. Techies are also mobile in nature – willing to travel further in the pursuit of higher income. It comes as no surprise then that the highest-skilled workers are more likely to end up in one of the large technological clusters with a strong inflow of FDI.

For these clusters, what impact does Foreign Direct Investment activity have on wages and employment? Prof. Nigel Driffield and his fellow researchers set out to explore this. Their analysis spans six research-intensive sectors including chemicals, pharmaceuticals, computers, electronics, R&D and other scientific activities in 28 European countries over a 9-year period (2002-2010). For them, Europe is a great research setting, the EU members plus Norway constituting the 2nd largest single market in the world, with free movement of labour and free trade.

At the same time, substantial differences are present at both national and regional levels, among them the availability of high-skilled workers, innovation capacity and the amount of attracted FDI. As a general rule, the effect of FDI is usually regarded as positive – thanks to the inflow of cash from abroad, local companies benefit from transfer of technology and expertise. However, it is not so straightforward as it might seem, because intra-firm technology transfer may also generate a productivity gap between foreign and local firms. And in this case, local firms will struggle to prevent their workers from leaving for a better-paid foreign firm, subsequently having to offer higher wages or reduce their workforce.

The stats show that an increase in FDI in high-tech sectors was accompanied by an annual 5% rise in domestic wages during 2002-2010 and that over the same period domestic employment grew only by 1.1% per annum – a glaring example of how foreign activity can actually squeeze skilled labour out of the domestic market.

The impact of Foreign Direct Investment on the labour market

Foreign Direct Investment and hot labour markets: Raising the bar. In the Big Tech era, knowledge-intensive companies are attracting strong inflows of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI). Their rapid development is combined with the search for the best talent in order to maintain leadership.  Professor Nigel Driffield, Warwick Business School, explores the implications of this phenomenon in terms of impact on domestic employment and skilled labour earnings.

Does it mean that foreign investors are no longer welcome? Of course not. FDI can generate huge positive effects on local economies, not least – as formerly mentioned – the transfer of technology and expertise that provides enormous benefits for the local companies. Moreover, if a firm has a strong market position, high profitability and can positively manage a spillover effect, it can also absorb wage increases at almost no cost. In this case, FDI inflow eventually has a positive impact on profits.

So, what could help maximize benefits associated with FDI while offsetting their detrimental effects on local firms? According to Driffield et al, the key factors are labour market flexibility – how quickly firms can respond to changes – and the capacity to absorb spillovers – or how significant the firm’s potential for the productivity growth is. These two factors depend heavily on a number of internal criteria, including size of business and profitability. There is also an important external factor: the host country’s level of development. This plays a crucial role in moderating the ability of local firms to embrace foreign technology.  

All of these factors determine whether a ‘crowding out’ or a technology effect dominates – that is, whether domestic firms lose or gain from the presence of FDI. More developed economies tend to better withstand demand shocks, and have higher labour market and wage flexibility. On the contrary, less developed economies tend to be less resistant to the adverse effects of FDI, with lower flexibility and fewer capacities to quickly reallocate resources in response to required changes.

It’s all in a model 

In determining the level of flexibility of a labour market in a given region, it is necessary to consider the role of market institutions. They can help draw a line between more liberal market economies and coordinated market economies. Prof. Driffield and his colleagues distinguish four distinct groups: Nordic/Anglo Saxon, Continental, Mediterranean and Transition economies.

Mediterranean countries have higher levels of labour market protection and segmentation. The Nordic model is characterized by high levels of social protection and welfare provision. In the Anglo-Saxon model, unions are weak and wages have a bigger dispersion. And in continental countries such as Belgium, Germany and France, there are stronger unions, and relatively higher levels of labour market segmentation. The graph below illustrates how each of these groups of countries differ in their flexibility and spillover absorb potential.

Labour market flexibility and capacity to absorb spillover. The graph illustrates how each of these groups of countries differ in their flexibility and spillover absorb potential.

In general, liberal market economies have higher levels of labour market flexibility. Anglo Saxon/Nordic countries have both the highest market flexibility and capacity to absorb spillovers, with their firms more likely to benefit from FDI without experiencing negative consequences on domestic wages and employment. On the other side of the scale there are the Mediterranean economies – more exposed to negative spillover effects. In those regions, foreign activity is more likely to push wages upwards and crowd out domestic employment.

Foreign Direct Investment: A roadmap for policymakers

Understanding FDI effects on labour markets may be interesting for both national and regional policymakers. It can help them understand how to make the most of incoming FDI – and at the same time how to protect local firms from adverse spillover effects.

Prof. Driffield and his colleagues point to the need to first and foremost understand what kind of market you are dealing with. If the market is more rigid – as in the cases of Transition or Mediterranean economies – governments should think about how to improve flexibility. This suggests, for example, putting emphasis on education and training as well as supporting small local firms.

National policies that promote domestic R&D investment and innovation strategies are also helpful in turning foreign activity to one’s own advantage, contends Prof. Driffield. After all, R&D and innovation enhance local firms’ productivity and capacity to exploit spillovers. At the same time, higher domestic R&D and innovation are likely to raise the attractiveness of a region for foreign investors. Tax credits, direct subsidies, collaborations between universities and firms all increase the available pool of high-skilled labour and support regional development.

The global ‘war for talent’ puts upward pressure on the earnings of that talent. And regions with a strong FDI inflow will not be immune to these increasing wage costs. The ultimate goal of policymakers is not to prevent foreign investors from pouring their money into local economies, but to augment the positive effects of such activities. The potential is in fact huge, and for many economies across the globe is yet to be discovered.

Nigel Driffield, Warwick Business School
Nigel Driffield

Useful links:

Learn more about the Council on Business & Society

The Council on Business & Society (The CoBS), visionary in its conception and purpose, was created in 2011, and is dedicated to promoting responsible leadership and tackling issues at the crossroads of business and society including sustainability, diversity, ethical leadership and the place responsible business has to play in contributing to the common good.  

Member schools are all “Triple Crown” accredited AACSB, EQUIS and AMBA and leaders in their respective countries.

The Council on Business & Society member schools:
- Asia-Pacific: Keio Business School, Japan; School of Management Fudan University; China; ESSEC Business School Asia-Pacific, Singapore.
- Europe: ESSEC Business School, France; IE Business School, Spain; Trinity Business School, Ireland; Warwick Business School, United Kingdom.
- Africa: Stellenbosch Business School, South Africa; ESSEC Africa, Morocco. 
- South America: FGV-EAESP, Brazil.

Leave a Reply

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.